Showing posts with label letters. Show all posts
Showing posts with label letters. Show all posts

A letter from 1981

Thirty years ago, when cuts in public expenditure were once again1 at the centre of a controversial policy to reduce the level of public sector borrowing, 364 economists famously signed a letter of protest to The Times. Professor Robert Neild2 was one of its authors.
In 1981, my colleague Frank Hahn and I wrote a letter criticising Mr Howe’s budget. We intended to send it, signed by the two of us, to The Times, but it grew into a 'statement' signed by 364 economists which created rather a stir when it was published. I shall recount how that came about and how I now see the episode in retrospect. At 87 my memories, filtered by age, are clear but of course subjective. I have referred to documents and statistics of the period to the best of my ability.
The monetarist debate
The statement was a climax in the Keynesian:monetarist debate, the nature of which it is worth briefly recalling.
Keynes’s great contribution to economics was a causal explanation why aggregate demand in an economy may not match its productive potential with the consequence that there is unemployment — or inflation. In The General Theory, published in 1936, he thus led us to understand why unemployment had plagued the world in the inter-war years.3 Then in How to Pay for the War, published in 1940, he estimated how much civilian demand would need to be restrained by budgetary means if war expenditure was to be met without inflation.4 In doing so, he pioneered the use of national income accounts in macro-economic management.
With few exceptions, economists accepted his theory. It is logically coherent; it relates to measurable variables (in the national income and expenditure accounts); and it recognises the importance of psychology, in particular the ‘animal spirits’ of entrepreneurs: it is rational and realistic.
For twenty-five years after WWII budgetary policy was based on demand management using Keynesian analysis: the probable course of aggregate demand was forecast and the balance in the budget was set so as bring aggregate demand towards the full employment level. The technique was far from perfect but the result was low unemployment, moderate inflation and real growth of 2 per cent a year.
This period of relative economic harmony was shattered in the 1970s when inflation exploded, triggered by sharply higher prices for oil and by the reaction of the trades unions to the consequent squeeze on real wages. The annual rate of inflation hit a peak of 24 per cent in 1975 and averaged 14 per cent a year in that decade.5 British governments, reluctant to reduce aggregate demand so as to cause unemployment to the point where money wages were checked, tried negotiating incomes policies with the trades unions and employers. They had little success: there were strikes and social unrest.
It was against that background that monetarist doctrine was adopted by Sir Keith Joseph and other Conservatives in the 1970s and became part of the policies that were evolved in that period and applied to the economy when Mrs Thatcher came to power in 1979. The evangelist of the doctrine was Milton Friedman. His message, like that of other evangelists, was wonderfully simple. Unions were not to blame for inflation, nor oil sheiks. It was all the result of excessive expansion of the money supply: ‘inflation can be mastered. The technical instruments for controlling the money supply are available. The obstacle is lack of political will.’6 The policy would involve high unemployment only temporarily since the economy, being self-regulating, would soon return to the ‘natural rate of unemployment’. The message was supported by a graph or graphs showing that over time prices and the money supply move approximately together.
The doctrine had two flaws. First, demonstrating that the money supply and prices move together is no better than showing that the length of life and the number of meals a person has eaten move together: simple association between two variables tells us nothing about causation. Secondly, the causal explanations that Friedman offered did not bear scrutiny.
At the beginning of 1980 Frank Hahn and I criticised monetarist doctrine on these grounds in an article in The Times, ‘Monetarism: why Mrs Thatcher should beware’.7 We quoted Milton Friedman’s view that unemployment would revert to a natural rate which ‘…is the level that would be ground out by the Walrasian system of general equilibrium equations, provided there is embedded in them the actual structural characteristics of the labour and commodity markets, including market imperfections….’ and explained that:
a. In the previous decade mathematical economists had shown that, even if there were no market imperfections, the Walrasian equations could not be expected to produce a general equilibrium with full employment.
b. The idea that they would do so in the presence of market imperfections, which abound in reality, was even more far fetched.
We concluded:
There are neither theoretical foundations nor empirical support for the monetarists’ proposition that the real economy is self-regulating and that activity and employment can be relied upon to recover automatically from the present fiscal and monetary squeeze.
It is not our purpose to propound or debate alternative policies here. Indeed we have held different opinions about policy in the past and might well do so again were we to debate it now. Our common concern is that the Government's policy, as well as analysis and debate of alternatives, should not be based on a misleading notion of how the economy works.
In a rather aggressive reply a week later Milton Friedman accused us of writing about the ‘Phillips Curve’, to which we had made no reference. After this diversion, he went on to say ‘We can know that a bird flies and have some insight into how it is able to do so without having a complete understanding of the aerodynamic theory involved.’ and listed a series of points to the effect that there was an historical association between money and prices with variable time lags. Without offering any better causal explanation than that, he reasserted in remarkably strong terms his view that the economy would recover automatically from the monetary squeeze:
…reduced monetary growth such as Mrs Thatcher’s government is trying to achieve, may increase unemployment temporarily, to be rewarded by a much sharper reduction in unemployment later.8
That was the doctrinal background to our letter.
The economic background was that unemployment was rising to levels not seen since the inter-war years. Since the war, the central objective of economic policy had been full employment, which had come to mean a rate of unemployment of 3 per cent or less, and that had been pretty well maintained until the 1970s. When unemployment rose to 7 per cent in 1980 and to 10 per cent in 1981, I certainly felt morally indignant that the great achievement of modern economics — the creation of full employment in place of the mass unemployment and the misery of the pre-war years, which I could remember — was being betrayed. I believe most economists felt the same. The feelings of the 364 economists were surely roused by further fiscal tightening in the 1981 budget when unemployment was already so high.
There was a further contributory cause that I hesitate to mention since it is personal. I do so because it is germane to understanding what happened. It is that Milton Friedman, who was very clever and made original contributions to economics, was an exceptionally artful debater whose rhetorical skills in the advocacy of monetarism were such that some politicians embraced him as a saviour offering a painless escape from inflation, whilst some economists saw him as a charlatan.9
At this time I was invited by the BBC to debate monetarism with him live on television. I was forewarned by my next-door neighbour Elaine Sofer (a sociologist, aughter of Benjamin Graham, the father of modern equity investment theory) that Friedman was a dangerous opponent in debate. She, when helping as a student to organise debates at Chicago University, had found that he was a most brilliant and enthusiastic debater. He did not mind being asked at short notice to take part in a debate, and typically would consent before asking what the subject was. If told that it was, say, capital punishment, he would say ‘Great, which side?’ and perform brilliantly whichever side he was on. Although forewarned, I found the way he avoided saying what caused the historical association between money and prices by means of prevarication and mockery so maddening that I lost my temper with him on the live programme. The shame I felt at making a public exhibition of myself imprinted the episode in my memory.
The relative importance of these three strands of opinion — that monetarism was theoretically incoherent, that unemployment was already shamefully high, and that Friedman was behaving as a charlatan — will have differed from person to person; and other considerations may also have been in their minds. But as I remember those days, these were the dominant reasons why so many economists signed the statement. How it came into being was this.
The statement 
After the budget, Frank Hahn and I, over coffee at the Faculty of Economics, set about drafting a joint letter to The Times criticising its monetary foundations. Others wanted to join and add their names till they were so numerous that I telephoned The Times to see how many signatures they would publish. Since the number wanting to sign exceeded the limit, the alternative evolved of turning the letter into a statement and inviting economists in all the universities in the country to sign it. I was amazed at the huge response.
The statement, which in essence repeated what Frank and I had said a year before in The Times, was as follows:
Faculty of Economics and Politics, 
Sidgwick Avenue, Cambridge 
28 March 1981
The following statement on economic policy has been signed by 364 university economists in Britain, whose names are given on the attached list:
‘We, who are all present or retired members of the economics staffs of British universities, are convinced that:
a) there is no basis in economic theory or supporting evidence for the government’s belief that by deflating demand they will bring inflation permanently under control and thereby induce an automatic recovery in output and employment;
b) present policies will deepen the depression, erode the industrial base of our economy and threaten its social and political stability;
c) there are alternative policies; and

d) the time has come to reject monetarist policies and consider urgently which alternative offers the best hope of sustained economic recovery.’
Analysis
Those who signed include:
The statement was circulated as university terms were ending. The rates of response have therefore been influenced by when term ended, by how dispersed is the community of university teachers in the vacation, as well as by the climate of opinion in each university.

Origins
The statement was sent by us to one member of each university on 13 March which said:
‘We believe that a large number of economists in British universities, whatever their politics, the government’s present economic policies to be wrong and that, for the sake of the country — and the profession — it is time we all spoke up. We have therefore prepared the attached statement cast in terms which we hope will command wide agreement.’
The aftermath 
In March 1984, the third anniversary of the statement, I was one of six of the signatories that were asked to say what they now thought about the statement. The rate of unemployment was now at 12 per cent, which proved to be the peak: it remained above the figure of 10 per cent till the end of 1987. Inflation had fallen from a peak of 18 per cent in 1980 to five per cent in 1984. Similarly the rate of increase in wage rates had fallen from 18 in 1980 to six per cent in 1984. Commodity prices had eased. The rise in unemployment had clearly been accompanied by a swift decline in inflation; the economy seemed to have levelled out at a high level of unemployment.
My comment was this:
I see no reason to modify my view about how the economy works. The levelling-out in activity has been in large part induced by the government relaxation of consumer credit. That’s exactly what happened in previous stop-go cycles. The American recovery, induced by a budget deficit, has helped us too. I suspect that if you disentangle the figures the chancellor’s budget is expansionary.10
Today we can judge the budgets of that period by looking at the historical estimates of the cyclically-adjusted budget balance, (also called the ‘structural budget balance’) produced by the Office of National Statistics
We can now see that the budget was expanded by 1.5 per cent of GDP between the 1981-82 and 1983-84, a significant but not extreme change. The extent of the tightening that went before is extreme. Between 1978-79 and 1981-1982 (which reflects the first-year impact of the 1981 budget) the budget was tightened by no less than 6.3 per cent of GDP. By far the greater part of that tightening (4.9 per cent) was introduced in the 1981 budget.
The statement in retrospect
Paragraphs a) and c) were statements about economic theory. They said that there was no basis in economic theory or supporting evidence for the government's monetarist belief in an automatic recovery, and that there were alternative policies. These, I believe, remain irrefutable propositions.
Paragraph b) made the prediction that present policies would deepen the recession with adverse economic and political consequences. In fact unemployment remained above 10 percent for six years and, as noted above, reached a peak 12 per cent in early 1984. The recession did not deepen as much as we had predicted; nor did the economy recover within a period consistent with any reasonable interpretation of Friedman’s ‘variable time lags’. In a vulgar political debate over the consequences of monetarism the participants might call ‘Quits’.
Paragraph d) follows from the others and requires no comment.
To get a better understanding of what happened in this period, economic historians will need to trace causation from the exogenous variables in macroeconomics, the most important of which are actions taken by the government (including the central bank) that influence the level of demand, and changes in demand and commodity prices in the world economy, through to the responses of the economy as recorded in the national income accounts, the monetary statistics, and the statistics of unemployment and prices. They will never achieve a perfect explanation but they should be able to do better than I can now.
A few points are worth noting now:
  1. It is clear that after 1979 many changes in policy were made in pursuit of two aims that were sometimes in conflict: the desire to check inflation and the desire to liberate market forces in the credit markets and other parts of the economy. The expansion of consumer credit that helped to sustain demand in this period is an example.
  2. The Employment Acts of 1980 and 1982 and 1984 that cut the power of the trades unions must have contributed to the rapid decline in inflation.
  3. The monetarist doctrine of Friedman has now been abandoned in favour of trying to use interest rates to control inflation, not the money supply. It is recognised that the money supply is endogenous, not exogenous, a passive indicator of how the demand for loans is going, not a policy instrument — a view for which there is ample backing.11
Conclusion: the veil of monetarism 
That the pursuit of full employment might lead to inflation was widely foreseen. For example, Beveridge in his 1944 book, Full Employment in a Free Society, wrote:
There is a real danger that sectional wage bargaining, pursued without regard to its effect upon prices, may lead to a vicious spiral of inflation…..12
And in the same year the White Paper on Employment Policy warned that:
Action taken by the Government to maintain expenditure will be fruitless unless wages and prices are kept reasonably stable …..it will be essential that employers and workers should exercise moderation in wage matters…13
When inflation struck in Britain the necessary response was (a) a short hard dose of deflation and (b) a radical reform of the trades unions. A hard-headed Keynesian analysis, or common sense, would have led to that conclusion. But before 1979 Labour and Conservative governments jibbed at such harsh policies, and so did the great majority of economists of whom I was one. Much as I abhor the social philosophy of Mrs Thatcher (and her follower, Mr Blair) I now give her credit for having introduced these two controversial policies that were necessary to check inflation — though I deplore the fact that monetarism so blinded the government that it pressed home deflation too hard and too long.
Monetarism served as a veil for politicians and central bankers in that it permitted them to avoid saying that they were imposing deflation and causing unemployment so as to check inflation. Instead they could say that their aim was to check the money supply so as to stop inflation, with or without the rider that they believed with Friedman that temporary unemployment would correct itself. I believe that the Conservative politicians that directed economic policy in Britain at this time spoke to this effect with complete sincerity, since they appear to have been converts to Friedman’s faith. But that was not true universally. In the important case of the United States there is strong evidence that Paul Volcker who, as chairman of the Federal Reserve dominated monetary policy, adopted monetary targets cynically as the only means of getting away with the big increases in interest rates needed to check inflation. A detailed account by William Greider of how he did this was published in The New Yorker in 1987. Greider reports that when Henry Wallich, a member of the board of the Federal Reserve, was told by Volcker that he proposed to adopt money supply targets, he accused him of making a pact with the devil, to which Volcker replied, ‘Sometimes you have to deal with the devil.’ Later in the article Greider writes that ‘The monetarist alternative offered a clever solution to Volcker’s internal political dilemma: it would serve as a veil to cloak the tough decisions.’14 A biography of Volcker gives the same interpretation of his tactics.15

Now the idea that economies, including financial markets, are self-regulating has come round to smite us again, this time into a depression with no redeeming features.

A letter - from the Telegraph

How 364 economists got it totally wrong

12:01AM GMT 15 Mar 2006


In 1981, Britain was at an economic crossroads. Policies that the Conservative government, elected in 1979, had been implementing to deal with accelerating inflation and a spiralling national debt were not working. Borrowing was rising. Interest rates were moving ever higher. If things had gone on as they were, credibility in the British economy would have collapsed. Investors, firms and trade unions would not have believed that any future government could have restored fiscal and monetary discipline. Britain could have become like so many South and Central American countries in the 1970s and 1980s.
Instead, Margaret Thatcher and her Chancellor, Sir Geoffrey Howe, changed tack. The 1981 Budget increased taxes by £4 billion - an enormous sum in 1981 prices. This was extremely difficult for a government elected to cut taxes. But by showing a determination to cut borrowing, the government made it easier to control monetary policy, too, as interest rates could be reduced. This helped convince the markets, which were also worried that high borrowing would lead to high inflation, because in the 1970s governments had financed their deficits by printing money.
Mrs Thatcher and Howe faced stiff opposition to this Budget, not just from the Labour and Liberal parties, but also from their own back benches. Their determination was really put to the test, however, when 364 economists signed a letter to The Times stating that there was "no basis in economic theory or supporting evidence" for the policy that the Budget was seeking to implement, that it threatened Britain's "social and political stability", and that an alternative course must be pursued.
The whole of the academic establishment - including some luminaries of today - stood against the government. The 364 included Third-Way guru Anthony Giddens; the current Governor of the Bank of England; Monetary Policy Committee member Stephen Nickell; and former and future Nobel Prize winners. Only a brave few stood out against them. Indeed, it is said that Mrs Thatcher was asked in heated debate in the Commons whether she could even name two economists who agreed with her. She replied that she could: Patrick Minford and Alan Walters. As the story goes on, her civil servant said when she returned to Downing Street: "It is a good job he did not ask you to name three." In fact, there were one or two others who deserve mention, such as Terry Burns and Tim Congdon, as well as some journalists and politicians who stayed firm and argued the case for what would today be described as orthodox fiscal and monetary policies.
In many walks of life, we listen to experts with respect. Three hundred and sixty-four experts would normally command a lot of respect. But were the 364 wrong and, if so, why were they so wrong? It should be mentioned that some of the 364 would not have agreed with all the content of the letter. Nickell has said that he signed the letter because it was "the only game in town". He agreed with aspects of it, but did not agree with it in its totality. That is fair enough. The letter was wide-ranging. But the majority of its signatories probably did accept the letter in its entirety. Furthermore, Labour peer and signatory Maurice Peston has said that there would have been hundreds more queueing up to sign it if it had not been sent over Easter.
On the face of it, they were wrong. The economic recovery that the 364 said would not happen began more or less as soon as the letter appeared. Unemployment continued to rise, but this was in the face of a highly regulated and unionised labour market and wholesale industrial restructuring. A long-term fall in the rate of unemployment had to wait until labour market and trade union reforms became embedded some years later.
The 364 were wrong because they believed the Keynesian consensus of the time. Indeed, they taught it to nearly every undergraduate in the country. The textbooks used by nearly all British undergraduates did not pay any attention whatsoever to alternatives. It was as if economic theory began and ended with the naïve Keynesianism of Keynes's immediate followers.
Howe chose not to respond to the problems of the widening Budget deficit as his predecessors had, by managing it through distortionary controls or by ignoring it. He faced it head on and increased taxes. To the naïve Keynesians, the increased taxes would lead to further contraction in the economy and no hope of economic recovery. But they ignored the wider consequences. With government borrowing back on course, Howe could reduce interest rates at a time when they had been rising and when a high exchange rate had been crippling British industry. Thus lower government borrowing meant lower interest rates. This alleviated some of the pressure on industry.
These benefits were reinforced in the medium term because, instead of credibility collapsing, as it could have done had the U-turn the 364 demanded occurred, the government's policy became more credible. Gradually investors came to believe that necessary policies would be followed through and that they would work. They could plan on the basis of lower inflation, lower interest rates and a government that would repay its debt.
At the time, Minford described the 364's letter as a "dangerous and dishonest game". This is a strong charge against fellow academics, but is it justified? The charge of dangerous probably is. The government could well have caved in under the pressure generated by so many experts. If it had done so, the long-term consequences would have been catastrophic. Unemployment of three million would probably not have been avoided in the short term and, in the long term, steady decline would have been the best possible result.
The 364's letter also affected trade union "expectations". If unions expected the government to U-turn, they would expect higher inflation and ask for higher pay increases. This could have contributed to the growth in unemployment. But were the 364 dishonest? Here Minford suggests that the evidence that the Thatcher/Howe policies were both necessary and could work was before their eyes. The alternatives of incomes policy and reflation had been tested to destruction and had failed. The supporting theory and evidence for the Thatcher/Howe approach had been circulating for some time, especially in North America.
Due to the determination of a small number of politicians, backed up by a handful of academics, the government prevailed. Even the 1997 Labour Government decided to institutionalise the pursuit of sound money and fiscal policy by its fiscal rules and by making the Bank of England independent.
There are still many problems with the over-regulated British economy, which is stifled by high government spending. More than ever, Britain needs politicians who will stand up against the experts when there is a need to implement difficult policies. Thankfully we had such people 25 years ago, when the temptations to take the easy way out must have been so great: the consequences had alternative policies been pursued do not bear thinking about.


A letter 36 years ago - from the Guardian March 2006

Twenty-five years ago this week, a seminal event occurred that symbolised a profound change in British - even world - economic policy. In response to Sir Geoffrey Howe's contractionary budget of March 1981, a letter was signed by 364 academic economists, denouncing the central tenets of Thatcherite economic strategy. 

Most of the luminaries of the British economic establishment were signatories, including Mervyn King, who became the present governor of the Bank of England. I am happy to say that I narrowly missed signing the letter, having not been asked to do so. 

At the time, Britain was not only in its deepest recession since the second world war but was also suffering from sky-high inflation. 

The key points of the letter were that inflation would not be controlled "by deflating demand", that output would not necessarily recover even if inflation were controlled, and that Conservative policies would "deepen the depression ... and threaten our political stability". 

The letter of the 364 coincided almost precisely with the moment the recession hit bottom. 

That coincidence allowed the Tories of the 1980s to turn the economists into 364 laughing stocks, and it hastened the demise of Keynesianism as the dominant economic philosophy of the era. 

Yet many of the 364 insist that they were right all along. Looking back at the 50 years since Britain's economy emerged from its postwar straitjacket, it is clear that 1981 marked a decisive break point. In the 25 years from 1956 to 1981, inflation was on a permanently rising curve, averaging 7.9%per annum over the entire period. 

In the quarter century since 1981, inflation has been generally declining, averaging only 4% overall. This has been achieved, as predicted by the Thatcherite monetarists, without any sacrifice to economic growth. 

From 1956-81, GDP growth averaged 2.3% per annum, and this has risen to 2.6% since 1981. Certainly, several key points made by the 364 were wrong. Inflation did come under control. 

There was no permanent depression. 

And political stability, after the miners' strikes at least, scarcely wobbled. In fact, Britain gradually lapsed into political torpor. 

Yet the 364 can make one counter claim. While GDP growth rebounded after 1981, it took a long time for unemployment to come down. In the Keynesian years from 1956-81, it averaged 3.7% of the labour force. 

From 1981 onwards, unemployment has never again approached that level, and has averaged a horrible 8.3%. Even after a decade and a half of expansion under the last two governments, the jobless rate has never once reached the levels that were achieved on average in the previous quarter century. 

So the monetarists were right that inflation could be brought down by the control of demand, rather than by direct controls over prices and incomes. 

They were probably right that output would recover after a demand shock, though perhaps not "automatically", as they claimed. But where they were really wrong was in claiming that the cost in terms of unemployment would also be temporary: 

25years in which it averaged 8.3% was one heck of a price to pay for their monetarist experiment.

From the Observer 4th June

On 8 June, voters will go to the polls for perhaps the most important UK general election since 1945. The importance arises in great part from profound differences in economic policy, reflecting different views of the nature and health of the British economy.
The Conservative manifesto calls for continued austerity, which will tend to slow the economy at a crucial juncture, against the backdrop of Brexit negotiations. Their spending cuts have hurt the most vulnerable and failed to achieve their intended debt and deficit reduction targets.
In contrast, Labour’s manifesto proposals are much better designed to strengthen and develop the economy and ensure that its benefits are more fairly shared and sustainable, as well as being fiscally responsible and based on sound estimations.
We point to the proposed increases in investment in the future of the UK and its people, labour market policies geared to decrease inequality and to protect the lower paid and those in insecure work and fair and progressive changes in taxation.
There is no future for the UK in a race to the bottom, which would only serve to increase social and economic inequality and further damage our social fabric. On the contrary, the UK urgently needs a government committed, as is Labour, to building an economy that really works “for the many, and not only the few”.

Dr Adotey Bing-Pappoe, lecturer in economics, Alan Freeman (personal capacity), Alfredo Saad Filho, Professor of Political Economy, SOAS University of London, Andrew Cumbers, Professor of Regional Political Economy, University of Glasgow, Andrew Simms, author of The New Economics, co-director New Weather Institute, Andy Ross FAcSS, Visiting Professor, Birkbeck University of London , Andy Kilmister, Department of Accounting, Finance and Economics, Oxford Brookes University, Ann Pettifor, Director of PRIME Economics (Policy Research in Macroeconomics), Dr Antonio Andreoni (PhD Cambridge), Senior Lecturer in Economics, SOAS University of London, Anwar Shaikh, Professor, New School for Social Research, USA, Arturo Hermann, Senior research fellow, Italian National Institute of Statistics, Rome, Italy, Professor Ben Fine, Department of Economics, SOAS University of London, Robert Rowthorn, Emeritus Professor of Economics, University of Cambridge., Bruce Cronin, Professor of Economic Sociology, Director of Research, Director of the Centre for Business Network Analysis, University of Greenwich, Dr Bruno Bonizzi, Lecturer in Political Economy, University of Winchester, Carlos Oya, Reader in Development Studies, SOAS University of London, Carolina Alves, PhD Economics, Carolyn Jones, Director, Institute of Employment Rights, Cem Oyvat, Lecturer, University of Greenwich, Christopher Cramer, Professor of the Political Economy of Development, SOAS University of London, Ciaran Driver FAcSS, Professor of Economics, SOAS University of London, Professor Colin Haslam, Professor of Accounting and Finance, Queen Mary University of London, Costas Lapavitsas, Professor of Economics, SOAS University of London, Cyrus Bina, Distinguished Research Professor of Economics, University of Minnesota, USA, Dr Dan O’Neill, Lecturer in Ecological Economics, University of Leeds, Daniela Gabor, Professor of Economics and Macro-Finance, University of the West of England, Daniele Archibugi, Professor, Birkbeck College, Professor Danny Dorling, University of Oxford, Writer and Academic, Dean Baker, Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research, Washington, DC, Dr Deborah Johnston Pro-Director (Learning and Teaching) SOAS (University of London), Diego Sánchez-Ancochea, Associate Professor in Political Economy, Director, Latin American Centre, University of Oxford, Dr Dimitris P. Sotiropoulos, The Open University Business School, Elisa Van Waeyenberge, Lecturer of Economics, SOAS University of London, Dr Emanuele Lobina, Public Services International Research Unit, University of Greenwich, Dr Faiza Shaheen, Economist (in a personal capacity), Frances Stewart, Professor of Development Economics and Director, Centre for Research on Inequality, Human Security and Ethnicity, University of Oxford, Gary Dymski, Professor of Applied Economics, Leeds University Business School, Geoff Harcourt, Honorary Professor, UNSW Australia, Gerald Epstein, Co-Director, Political Economy Research Institute, and Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst, USA, Dr Giorgos Galanis, Lecturer in Economics, Goldsmiths University, Gregor Semieniuk, Lecturer in Economics, SOAS University of London, Guglielmo Forges Davanzati, Associate professor of Political Economy, University of Salento, Italy, Dr Guy Standing FAcSS, Professorial Research Associate, SOAS University of London, Ha-Joon Chang, University of Cambridge, Hannah Bargawi, Lecturer in Economics, SOAS University of London, and Research Partner, Centre for Development Policy and Research, Dr Hassan Hakimian, Reader in Economics, SOAS University of London, Professor Dr Heiner Flassbeck, former Chief Economist of UNCTAD, Geneva, Heikki Patomäki, Professor of World Politics, University of Helsinki, Howard M. Wachtel, Professor Emeritus of Economics, American University, Washington, DC, USA, Howard Reed, Director, Landman Economics, Dr Hugh Goodacre, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of Westminster, Teaching Fellow, University College London, Hugo Radice, University of Leeds., Hulya Dagdeviren, Professor of Economic Development, University of Hertfordshire, Ilhan Dögüs, Department of Socioeconomics, University of Hamburg, Germany, James K. Galbraith, Professor of Government, University of Texas, USA, Jan Toporowski, Professor of Economics and Finance, SOAS University of London, Dr Jane Lethbridge, Public Services International Research Unit, University of Greenwich, Jeanette Findlay, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of Glasglow, Jeff Faux, Founder & former Director, Economic Policy Institute, Washington D C, Dr Jeff Powell, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of Greenwich, Dr Jeff Tan, Economist, Aga Khan University in the UK, Jeremy Smith, co-director, PRIME Economics (Policy Research in Macroeconomics), Dr Jo Michell, Senior Lecturer in Economics, UWE Bristol, Professor John Grahl, Economics Department, Middlesex University, John Palmer, former Political Director of the European Policy Centre, Dr Johnna Montgomerie, Senior Lecturer in Economics, Deputy Director of the Political Economy Research Centre, Goldsmiths University of London, Jonathan Dawson, Coordinator of Economics, Schumacher College, Professor Jonathan Michie, Professor of Innovation & Knowledge Exchange, University of Oxford , Dr Jonathan Perraton, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of Sheffield, Jorge Buzaglo, Associate Professor of Economics, University of Stockholm, Sweden, Dr Julian Wells, Principal Lecturer of Economics, Kingston University, Kate Bayliss, Research Fellow, Economics Department, SOAS University of London, Professor Kate Pickett, University of York Champion for Research on Justice & Equality, Dr Kevin Deane, Senior Lecturer in International Development, University of Northampton (personal capacty), Dr Kitty Stewart, Associate Professor of Social Policy, London School of Economics and Political Science, Klaus Nielsen, Professor of Institutional Economics, Birkbeck University of London, László Andor, Associate Professor, Corvinus University, Hungary, Leslie Huckfield, Yunus Centre for Social Business & Health, Glasgow Caledonian University, Malcolm Sawyer, Emeritus Professor of Economics, University of Leeds, Marco Veronese Passarella, Economics Division, Leeds University Business School, Maria Nikolaidi, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of Greenwich, Dr Mario Seccareccia, Full Professor, Department of Economics, University of Ottawa, Canada, Dr Martin Watts, Emeritus Professor of Economics, The University of Newcastle, Massoud Karshenas, Professor of Economics, SOAS University of London, Dr Matteo Rizzo, Senior Lecturer, Department of Economics, SOAS University of London, Mehmet Ugur, Professor of Economics and Institutions, University of Greenwich Business School, Michael Roberts, financial economist and author of The Long Depression, Professor Mushtaq Khan, Department of Economics, SOAS, University of London, Professor Ozlem Onaran, Director of Greenwich Political Economy Research Centre, University of Greenwich, Pallavi Roy, Lecturer in International Economics, SOAS, University of London, Paulo dos Santos, Assistant Professor of Economic, New School for Social Research, USA, Paul Mason, economics writer, Prem Sikka, Emeritus Professor of Accounting, University of Essex, Dr Pritam Singh, Professor of Economics, Oxford Brookes University, Radhika Desai, Professor, Department of Political Studies, University of Manitoba, USA, Richard McIntyre, Professor, Chair, Department of Economics, University of Rhode Island, USA, Richard Murphy, Professor of Practice in International Political Economy at City University of London and Director of Tax Research LLP, Richard Parker, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, USA, Richard Wilkinson, Emeritus Professor of Social Epidemiology, University of Nottingham, Dr Robert Calvert Jump, Lecturer in Economics, Kingston University, Robert Neild, Professor Emeritus of Economics, University of Cambridge, Robert Pollin, Distinguished Professor of Economics and Co-Director, Political Economy Research Institute, University of Massachusetts Amherst, USA, Roberto Veneziani, Queen Mary University of London, Susan Himmelweit, Emeritus Professor of Economics, Open University, Dr Sara Gorgoni, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of Greenwich, Dr Sara Maioli, Lecturer in Economics, Newcastle University, Dr Satoshi Miyamura, Lecturer in the Economy of Japan, SOAS University of London, Shawky Arif, The University of Northampton, Simon Wren-Lewis, Professor of Economic Policy, Oxford University, Professor Steve Keen, Department of Economics, Kingston University, Professor Engelbert Stockhammer, Kingston University, Simon Mohun, Emeritus Professor of Political Economy, Queen Mary University of London, Dr Sunil Mitra Kumar, Lecturer in Economics, King’s College London, Susan Newman, Senior Lecturer of Economics, University of West England, Dr Susan Pashkoff, Economist, Dr Suzanne J Konzelmann, Director, Postgraduate Programmes in Corporate Governance and Business Ethics, Director, London Centre for Corporate Governance and Ethics, Co-Executive Editor, Cambridge Journal of Economics, Tom Palley, Former Chief Economist, US-China Economic and Security Review Commission, Tomás Rotta, Lecturer in Economics, University of Greenwich, Trevor Evans, Emeritus Professor of Economics, Berlin School of Economics and Law, Germany, Will Davies, Reader in Political Economy, Goldsmiths, University of London, Dr William Van Lear, Economics Professor, Belmont Abbey College, USA, Yanis Varoufakis, Former Minister of Finance, Greece, Yannis Dafermos, Senior Lecturer in Economics, University of the West of England, José Gabriel Palma, University of Cambridge, Yulia Yurchenko, University of Greenwhich, Laurie Macfarlane, Economics Editor, Open Democracy, Meghnad Desai, London School of Economics, Clive Lawson, University of Cambridge, Professor Lawrence King, University of Cambridge